The Hiring Dilemma for High-tech Firms: 'Make vs. Buy'
One particular hiring conundrum is hardly a new one for those in human resource management: Is a company better off developing and training specialized workers in-house or hiring skilled workers from outside the company? The question is especially important in fast-paced, technology-based industries where investment in human capital is critical.
If firms need to augment the skill of their workforce to complement an investment in technology, they face a traditional 'make vs. buy' problem. Firms can "structure their HRM (human resource management) system to develop the necessary skills in-house or they can structure their HRM to attract workers with the necessary skills on the external market.
In response to this make vs. buy dilemma, experts think they have found the answer for industries that compete in cutting-edge technology. Using U.S. Census Bureau data recently made available to external researchers, they say that they have statistically demonstrated when companies should hire from outside and when they should develop from within.
The bottom-line is laying the foundation for how to think about technology and HR at the same time. HR strategy complements technology strategy, yet often people developing these strategies don't work together. This is especially true in younger firms. But if you want to be in a fast-paced industry, you need to invest in an HR system that gives you the skills you need. And it has to start at the CEO level. It has to come from the top down.
These issues will be increasingly relevant with time. More and more firms will be evolving to the spot market [external labor market] model. Most industries tend to operate in a faster-paced environment [than before]. Product life cycles across all manufacturing industries as a whole are growing shorter. Firms are facing more opportunities for change and more adjustments to the workforce. When skills need to be adjusted, it pays to buy the skills instead of developing them. And as all industries evolve, we can easily predict we will be seeing more and more firms adopting the buy strategy.
The Hewlett Packard Case
Using examples from the semiconductor industry, the following scenarios can be seen. If a firm is faced with significant marketplace and technological changes, it is better off hiring workers from the outside labor market who have the skills it needs, rather than investing in developing those skills inside the firm. Examples of such firms are found in the graphics chips industry, where leading companies like NVIDIA, VIA Technologies and ATI Technologies come out with a new product generation every 12 to 18 months. When product generations are short, there is not necessarily time to develop the necessary skills for the next generation in-house, so these companies benefit from hiring skills from the external labor market.
The opposite is true for slower moving industries operating in marketplaces with less change -- for instance, companies like Bosch and Delphi-Delco that manufacture automotive chips which often last four or five years before a new generation makes them obsolete. When product generations last a long time, it becomes feasible to develop talent in-house in preparation for the next product generation. It is better for these firms to take the long approach and develop the necessary skills within the firm.
The impact of these findings can be significant for human resource management strategies. As the pace of technological change has quickened, and as global competition has shortened product life cycles, firms have had to rethink their technology investment strategies and their human resource management practices in order to remain competitive.
A classic example of this phenomenon is Hewlett Packard over the last 20 years. They had such a reputation for these internal labor markets, where they hired employees at an early stage and then developed them throughout their careers. That was the company's reputation. But over the last 20 years, the Hewlett Packard way has eroded. They are now operating more on the spot market. In order to keep pace with other technology firms, they are forced to hire on the outside.
It is worth noting that although the relationship of technological change, compensation and tenure at the individual level has been well-studied, surprisingly little is known about the relationship between technological change and an (individual) firm's HRM decisions. Previous research on this topic has been either case study oriented or has utilized data from broad establishment-level surveys. But now we can connect these micro and macro approaches by using data that allows us to capitalize on the strengths of each type of research.
Pulling data from the Census Bureau's Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics (LEHD) Program, which covers seven large states from 1992 to 1997, we can specifically choose to look at the impact of R&D and HRM systems on firms' performance within the electronics industry, where technological investment is a critical strategic variable.
Although firms in the electronics industry have a high level of R&D investment relative to other industries, there is a large variance in investment between firms within the industry. This variance can be observed in the length of product life cycles: from 12 months for fast-evolving consumer-based products such as graphic chips, to five years or more for slowly-evolving analog products."
In the industries we are studying, 'cutting-edge' is such a complex term because there are so many facets of technology. Someone might have skills that are cutting-edge for some products, but another (level) in the industry wouldn't be interested in that worker. It becomes a problem of identifying the right workers, including some who may be undervalued by the current workplace.
Offer Training or Go Outside
Fnding and keeping talent as it relates to the electronics industry boils down to one main issue: Make vs. buy. To answer this question, researchers propose that companies analyze another question first: "How does the firm's product life, and thus its rate of R&D spending, affect how the HRM system operates?"
We assume that a new technology requires a mix of experience on the previous generation of technology and new skills that don't currently exist in the firm. We assume that experience and new skills are complements and firms differ in their mix of experienced and new workers. Technology firms in short product life markets, and thus with high R&D spending, must have a mix of engineers dominated by the new skills required for the new technology with a small emphasis on engineers with experience on the last generation of technology. Firms in long product life markets, and thus with low R&D spending, rely more on a workforce with experience since the firm has greater gains associated with cutting costs, improving quality, and improving throughput over the life of the product than the gains associated with developing a new product.
In short, firms must make two major decisions in creating the optimal skill-experience composition in the workforce: First, decide whether to provide formal training in the new technology to their existing workers or to purchase these skills through new hires, which is the essence of what they call the "make-buy decision;" and second, decide which experienced engineers and other workers to retain.
The firm makes the first decision based upon the relative costs, including both the payroll costs and the time-to-market costs, of making or buying the required skills for the new technology. "The cost of 'making' the required skills is the worker adjustment cost of acquiring skills (training costs) and is proportional to the size of technological jumps over a given time. The cost of 'buying' the required skills is the firm's adjustment costs in hiring new workers, which does not depend on the size of the technological jump.
Therefore, depending on the firm's underlying cost structures, for sufficiently large technological jumps, 'buying' will be less costly than 'making' new skills."
While high R&D firms are more likely to buy new skills compared to low R&D firms, there is an important caveat to this finding. There are experienced workers who have firm-specific knowledge that can't be replaced on the outside market. Research shows that high R&D firms in particular suffer if they lose too many experienced workers, which is why these firms must decide which experienced engineers and other workers to try and retain. Often, this can be a problem. When one is not investing a lot in developing the skills of a work force, [employees] will leave.
Research looks at many factors within human resource management practices that affect worker productivity, including performance incentives, multiple ports of entry, and low and high turnover rates. It compares different educational levels of workers; varying accession rates (ratio of total number of new hires to the total number of workers); separation rates for workers with two and five years of experience; standard deviation of earnings for various worker levels, and wage growth for workers with five years of experience. In order to characterize the human resource practices of a firm, researchers use earnings, earnings growth, accession rates and separation rates for selected cohorts within each firm.
And finally, they perform a cluster analysis of firms and HRM measures to identify and describe the four most common HRM systems that firms set up as a result of the make-buy and retention decisions:
· Bureaucratic ILM (Internal Labor Markets): Initial earnings of new hires are similar (low variance) since most workers enter at the same level and have similar (and reliable) earnings growth. Firm experiences a low separation rate.
· Performance-based ILM: Entry of workers and their initial earnings reflect skill requirements so average initial earnings of new hires are higher with higher variance than for bureaucratic ILM. After approximately two years, workers are selected (based upon performance) for faster career development and members of a cohort compete for entry into these favored positions, which have higher earnings growth and lower separation rates. Those who do not receive skill development have lower earnings growth and higher separation rates.
· Spot Market (External Labor Markets): Firms can identify workers' talents and skills, and hire and pay accordingly. Firm can monitor worker performance and pay worker according to contribution. Initial earnings and earnings growth reflect market rates for skill and talent, with large initial variance, and variance does not increase over tenure. Separation rate is higher than in ILMs.
· Spot Market with Rewards: Firms hire and pay workers in spot market, but identification of workers' talents and effort at hire is imperfect and monitoring of worker performance is imperfect. Variance of initial earnings is lower than in spot market. Firm must include performance rewards and tournament or wage-efficiency type incentives; thus variance of earnings increases over tenure. Earnings growth is higher than in spot market. Separation rate is higher than in spot market since the bad matches (both at hire and in rewards) end.
Ultimately, to conclude, it can be said that firms with high R&D that choose a Spot Market with Rewards HRM system will have higher worker productivity than those that choose other HRM systems. And firms with low R&D that choose Performance-based ILM HRM systems will have higher worker productivity than firms that choose other HRM systems. There are suggestions that a surprising" number of firms do the exact opposite of what the research showed was best.
These results suggest that high R&D firms are more likely to buy new skills compared to low R&D firms, and yet these high R&D firms suffer if they lose too many experienced workers.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Refer to previous case:
Solution to last issue case
SWOT Analysis
Strength Weakness
- Highly Innovative 1. High Technological Up gradation
- Revolutionize Inventory 2. Huge cost incurred
Management
Opportunity Threat
- Cost cutting 1.May breach privacy
- Promote smart products 2. Adverse people perception
Recommendation and suggestion:
- Go by RFID TECHNOLOGY. It may be one time investment but it will be beneficial in long run.
- Formulate laws and rules to counter misuse of RFID technology.
- Spread general awareness in public ,spread the information of advantages of RFID.
- Eliminate any controversial use of RFID